Modernizing Indonesia’s Financial Sector
Please note that we are not authorised to provide any investment advice. The content on this page is for information purposes only.
Reforms of the financial sector in Indonesia since 1997 have mitigated the key risk factors that caused the economic crisis of 1997. The first of these was structural weaknesses in the financial sector, particularly the banking system. The second was heavy borrowing by both the banking system and the corporate sector from foreign sources. Indonesia’s Central Bank had warned that the risk of losses due to the currency exchange rate of private and state-owned companies’ foreign debts are still high and continue to haunt throughout 2015.
Reforms of the financial sector in Indonesia since 1997 have mitigated the key risk factors that caused the economic crisis of 1997. The first of these was structural weaknesses in the financial sector, particularly the banking system. The second was heavy borrowing by both the banking system and the corporate sector from foreign sources. Indonesia’s Central Bank had warned that the risk of losses due to the currency exchange rate of private and state-owned companies’ foreign debts are still high and continue to haunt throughout 2015.
In 1997, Indonesia’s budget almost balanced. This was the result of tight fiscal and debt rules, as overseas development assistance from a consortium of Indonesia’s Western creditors financed the entire budget deficit. The current account deficit was also manageable at around 3–4 percent of GDP.
However, this did not prevent the crisis.
The banking sector is the core of the financial industry in Indonesia and the main source of external financing for the corporate sector. In January–February 1998, the banking system collapsed. Bank runs and capital flight drained foreign exchange reserves. Not even Bank Indonesia (BI), the central bank, could provide loans of more than a few months maturity. Interest rates rose to over 80 percent in 1997. Inflation rose to 58 percent in 1998 and the economy shrank by over 13.1 percent.
Four weaknesses in the financial system explain Indonesia’s capitulation to crisis. First, the undercapitalisation of the banking system left it open to risk. Second, there was substandard regulation and supervision, particularly in enforcing compliance with capital adequacy ratios and legal lending limits, and vigilance about foreign exchange exposure and derivatives. Third was a lack of inter-bank competition. Public sector wealth (including that of state-owned enterprises) was exclusively deposited with a group of state-owned banks, which controlled over 60 percent of the market. Fourth, the availability of cheap credit from state-owned banks with low risk provided no incentive for the corporate sector to raise funds in the capital and bond markets.
BI records foreign borrowings of banks, but there were regular violations of regulations on borrowing. There were no records of foreign borrowings if the corporate sector. Nearly all corporate foreign borrowings were short term, unhedged and used to finance long-term projects in non-traded sectors of the economy. These were mainly land-based industries that only generate income in rupiah. This caused double maturity mismatches, namely: currency and maturity.
The crisis ended financial repression practised during the 32-year rule of President Suharto. Under Suharto, the government set specific credit ceilings concerning the use of credit, which were applicable by economic sector, class of customer and individual borrowers. Interest rates were set below inflation rates and Askrindo, the state-owned credit insurance company, BI and the Ministry of Finance assumed credit risk.
Between 1997 and 2013, the Indonesian government adopted a number of policies to rebuild and modernise Indonesia’s financial sector.
The first policy was to provide emergency liquidity and purchase sovereign bonds to restore capital adequacy of financially distressed banks. Non-viable banks immediately closed or restructured. To clean up their books, viable banks restructured sour assets, while the government took over their foreign liabilities.
The second policy was to create a banking safety net through a deposit guarantee. This restored public confidence in the banking system and stopped destabilising bank runs in 1997.
The third strategy was to overhaul regulatory oversight by adopting risk-oriented banking supervision according to Basel principles and by reforming the accounting system. Modelled after the Financial Sector Authority of the UK, the OJK (Otoritas Jasa Keuangan, Financial Services Authority) came about in 2010 to regulate and supervise all financial sectors. BI focuses on macroeconomic prudential policies to guard against systemic risk. The Financial Stability Forum, created in 2007, facilitates cooperation, coordination and exchange of information between the Ministry of Finance, BI and the state-owned Credit Insurance Company (LPS) to maintain financial stability. Nevertheless, institutions and the legal system remain weak as they cannot properly protect private property rights or enforce business contracts.
Fourth was to modernise the payment system by introducing real time gross settlements and modern communication technologies to ensure interbank transactions are timely and safe. This reduces the need for cash, excess reserves and overdrafts. Previously, under the Suharto administration, these technologies were only available to Bank Central Asia, owned jointly by Suharto’s family and business cronies.
The fifth strategy has been to restructure BI and the banking system. Modelled after the Bundesbank of Germany, BI became an independent institution in 1999 with a single objective: to achieve the target inflation rate.
The sixth policy was to partially privatise the state-owned banks, while keeping a controlling stake in state hands. Indonesia’s state-owned banks remain heavily protected and are public sector failures with weak governance.
Lastly, the government ended financial repression and floated sovereign bonds. This helped to both recapitalise the banking system and finance budget deficits that encouraged the development of capital and bond markets. The end of cheap credit with its subsidised interest rate and low credit risk provides an incentive for the corporate sector to raise funds in these markets. Indonesia has no strong institutional investors to absorb sovereign bonds. At present, nearly 40 percent of liquidity in domestic capital and bond markets is volatile, short-term capital inflows.
It is through these policies that the Indonesian government has effectively reduced risks and moved Indonesia towards a modern financial system.
How Indonesia reformed its risky financial sector is republished with permission from East Asia Forum